|
In Ben Bernanke's book, the Great Depression wasn't really the result of crashing markets, shuttered factories, and millions of homeless. No. The problem was that markets for liquidated assets of bankruptcies and home foreclosures weren't sufficiently "efficient" in the 1930s. Not efficient way back then, of course, but we know better now, don't we? No wonder we're in this mess, again. No wonder Bush picked Ben Bernanke to succeed a fleeing Alan Greenspan. Bernanke made his name as an economist after he published a paper about the role of bankruptcies in recessions. In the June 1983 American Economic Review, the future Fed Chairman wrote that the reason the 1929-33 recession turned into systemic bank failure and a Great Depression was that bankers didn't have enough information about the returns they could realize from liquidating customer assets. Bernanke offered a nice, neat explanation for why the Great Depression lasted so long. The freeze-up in the credit markets that resulted in the March 10, 1933 "Bank Holiday" was unnecessarily protracted and severe because markets for the disposal of bankruptcies and foreclosures were insufficiently developed. Lenders, not having sufficient information about the money they could have been making, essentially stopped lending. That, he surmised, snowballed into a deep, downward spiral of industrial failure, protracted unemployment, and lowered output of goods and services. In other words, what bankers didn't know about bankruptcy could destroy the American economy. And, did. And, did again. . . The solution Bernanke suggested is more up-to-date and accurate reporting of distress sales -- i.e., a well-managed recession under all-seeing Fed supervision. No need for any fundamental reforms in banking practices or intervention to assist homeowners. The market is perfect, bankers are perfect, and with enough information they will surely correct themeselves. Bottom line, the Fed Chairman thought that jobless recovery and the mortgage crisis were quite manageable (not a real problem) and that the answer was an efficient reporting system and market for foreclosures.You're a great humanitarian, Ben. Tell that to six million Americans who will be out in street by the end of the year because of your policies, and because Congress will drag its feet in granting relief to distressed homeowners. Bernanke's thinking can be discerned quite plainly by the second page of Bernanke's 1983 paper, which is surprisingly readable. See, Ben S. Bernanke, "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 73(3), pages 257-76, June. http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/docs/MeltzerPDFs/bernon83.pdfHere's a string of citations that shows the evolution of Bernanke's thinking on the subject. His emphasis on bankruptcy is clearly seen in a paper he wrote two years earlier, Article Bernanke, Ben S, 1983. "Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in Propagation of the Great Depression," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 73(3), pages 257-76, June. (restricted) This item is featured on the following reading lists: Barro, Robert J, 1978. "Unanticipated Money, Output, and the Price Level in the United States," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 86(4), pages 549-80, August. (restricted) Sargent, Thomas J, 1976. "A Classical Macroeconometric Model for the United States," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 84(2), pages 207-37, April. (restricted) Bernanke, Ben S, 1981. "Bankruptcy, Liquidity, and Recession," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 71(2), pages 155-59, May. Stiglitz, Joseph E & Weiss, Andrew, 1981. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 71(3), pages 393-410, June. (restricted) Lucas, Robert Jr., 1972. "Expectations and the neutrality of money," Journal of Economic Theory, Elsevier, vol. 4(2), pages 103-124, April. (restricted) Abel, Andrew B. & Mishkin, Frederic S., 1983. "An integrated view of tests of rationality, market efficiency and the short-run neutrality of monetary policy," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 11(1), pages 3-24. (restricted) Other versions: Andrew B. Abel & Frederic S. Mishkin, 1983. "An Integrated View of Tests of Rationality, Market Efficiency, and the Short-Run Neutrality of Monetary Policy," NBER Working Papers 0726, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (restricted) Fama, Eugene F., 1980. "Banking in the theory of finance," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 6(1), pages 39-57, January. (restricted) Douglas W. Diamond & Philip H. Dybvig, 2000. "Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity," Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, issue Win, pages 14-23. Other versions: Diamond, Douglas W & Dybvig, Philip H, 1983. "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity," Journal of Political Economy, University of Chicago Press, vol. 91(3), pages 401-19, June. (restricted) Robert J. Gordon & James A. Wilcox, 1981. "Monetarist Interpretations of the Great Depression: An Evaluation and Critique," NBER Working Papers 0300, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. (restricted) Full references
|