|
Edited on Mon Feb-23-09 11:47 AM by Kurt_and_Hunter
A person bought a house in 2006 for $500K. Today it is worth $350K.
A few years from now it might be worth $450K or it might be worth $250K.
In the first case it is possible that helping her stay in that house helps the overall market, and helps her.
In the second case helping her stay in her house simply cements her utter financial destruction.
Over most of the last 30-40 years home prices were sensitive to how much money people made. The median home price was three times the median household income. When people made more money houses went up accordingly. Over the last 10-12 years housing decoupled from income. Housing prices went up, up, up while household incomes stayed flat.
The US median income in 2007 (last year available) was $50,233. Given high unemployment and asset deflation I think it is safe to assume that current median household income is not higher than that.
The median home price in November 2009 was $209K. That is after "collapsing."
Even discounting the fact that deflationary events over-shoot the mark it is distinctly possible that housing has only begun its slide and has another 30% to go.
Another data point: Rental prices used to track sale prices quite closely. Rental prices did not, however, participate in the boom in any big way. The fact that a house might go way up in price offers value to the owner but not the renter. Home owners are paying an average 40% extra to own versus the cost of renting an equivalent property. That is, IMO, unsustainable. That ownership premium is based on the assumption that home prices will appreciate at a ferocious clip. There is certainly no reason for it in the current market. In fact, people should be paying a stiff premium not to own. When prices are going down ownership is dangerous and renting *should* carry a risk-premium. (The renter gets the benefit of the house without carrying any of the risk of its deflation as an asset.)
Another data point: In Japan housing was throttled down to pre-boom levels. Since burst bubbles typically drive the assets in question down to pre-bubble levels that is what one would expect. What are pre-boom housing prices in the US? A lot lower than they are now. Certainly not 2002 prices! 1992 is closer.
Always remember that all previous home prices had a premium for anticipated appreciation that was, given what we know now, unwarranted. All 1990s housing prices that did not have a future housing collapse built in were faulty. This is an important concept. Even before the bubble people had an expectation that housing is a safe buy and tends to appreciate. That was built into prices. Nobody today thinks about housing they way they did in 2002, 1992 or even 1962. Nobody still thinks real estate is always a safe investment and that will be built into all housing prices going forward. If people in 1995 could see where we are today housing would have been cheaper in 1995 than it was.
There are condos in Tokyo today that are still underwater from their 1988 valuation!
re: "People bought too much house." Some people did, of course, but some people always have. But most people at the heart of this problem did not buy too much house at all. Let's revisit our $500K home buyer whose house is now worth $350K. She lives in a $350K house, not a $500K house. Things are worth what they are worth. If she has the same job today she has an income that qualified for $500K but lives in a house worth $350K. She is certainly not living beyond her means. Quite the opposite! She is living in "less house" than her income warrants. Keep in mind that the house has the same number of bathrooms whether the market says it's $500K or $250K. (Take that, Rick Santelli.) The reality is that she bought too much debt, not too much house. In 2006 she bought a house she could afford at the market price at the time. That's not very sinister behavior.
So now she pays a $500K mortgage every month on a $350K house. She is not facing foreclosure but her household net worth is down $150K. That has to be made up. Since she can not count on ever getting $500K for her house she has to greatly increase her retirement savings as percentage of her income to make up the difference. She cannot spend money. And even if she were inclined to spend wildly she cannot since she can no longer borrow money against her underwater house. (Actually it is even worse than that. She has to save to build up enough money to buy her way out of her house! If she needs to move she will have to either default or write the bank a check for $50K or whatever it works out to. So forget retirement... she has to save just to have the option of ever escaping her house!)
We are talking about the best case home-owner... she can pay her mortgage every month and will not face foreclosure unless the is laid off.
Anyway, the upshot of what I'm saying is that housing may bounce off the $200K median level (it could happen...) or housing could do what one would sensibly expect: go to 3 times median household income--which was the norm even in GOOD times-- with monthly rent and mortgage payments on comparable properties returning to the same range.
I don't see any reason to assume that housing will not decline an additional 20%-40%. Maybe it won't, but the argument for return to 1993 valuations is a lot more compelling than the case for housing prices stabilizing at levels unsupported by 1) incomes, or 2) a built-in expectation of dramatic appreciation.
QUESTION: If housing is going to decline another 30% what are the policy implications?
|